Monday, January 30, 2023

Adani - Who bombed Iran? - btbirkett@gmail.com - Gmail

Who bombed Iran? - btbirkett@gmail.com - Gmail

   

For years, India’s Adani Group, an Indian conglomerate and the world’s largest private developer of coal plants, faced repeated allegations of corruption, money laundering, and theft of taxpayer funds. Those claims tended to be of local origin, and they triggered low-level investigations that usually went away. Meanwhile, Gautam Adani, 60, continued to amass his wealth, becoming critical to India’s infrastructural expansion under powerful Prime Minister Narendra Modi. Known as “Modi’s Rockefeller,” Adani is now Asia’s wealthiest man.

US probe leads to scandal. Now, Adani’s family-run energy and transport empire has been slammed with a US-based investigation by Hindenburg Research. The New York-based financial forensics investigator has cited evidence of suspected money laundering, stock manipulation, and tax fraud, causing Adani Group’s market value to tumble. Crucially, the report also raises questions about Adani’s proximity to his friend and ally, Modi.

Starting off with diamonds and commodities, Adani is now the coal king of India. Despite protests and regulations against the use of dirty fossil fuel, the first-generation entrepreneur has also expanded into defense, media, and cement, but much of his money has come from energy and infrastructure contracts, many of them tendered during the Modi era. While the relationship between the two men has been under scrutiny for years, the widely cited Hindenburg investigation doesn’t just detail the extent of Adani’s misdoings, but it also claims he couldn’t have gotten so far without the government stonewalling regulators and supporting his expansion.

Modi’s been silent about his ties to Adani, but he has reportedly nurtured a connection with him since the 1990s. Before Modi was PM, he was the chief minister of Gujarat, the same state where Adani got his start and where one of Modi’s major gifts to him was land at a throwaway price, which essentially became the launchpad for Adani’s biggest power moves.

Monday, January 16, 2023

Is Elon Musk Coachable? - RHR | Senior Leadership Development

Is Elon Musk Coachable? - RHR | Senior Leadership Development

..These are the types of topics we would entertain and explore. To enter a coaching engagement, the leader does not necessarily have to have all the answers to the questions I posed, but they need to be open to exploring them, as well as be humble enough to put their vulnerabilities on the table.

...Social media companies are not meant to be contained; they thrive on the network effect and are the social fabric of community and voice. The goal is to lose control of the conversation in order to connect and leverage the network effect. 

Hum Capital thinks the future of funding is a return to old-school Wall Street | TechCrunch

Hum Capital thinks the future of funding is a return to old-school Wall Street | TechCrunch

Saturday, January 14, 2023

Investing in Commercial Real Estate in 2023: A Market in Dislocation

Investing in Commercial Real Estate in 2023: A Market in Dislocation

...Not only is debt historically expensive, it's also exceedingly difficult to obtain. Dysfunctional capital markets are currently so debilitating to certain deals that some developers and operators are opting to forego using debt altogether. In industry parlance, we refer to this strategy as “unlevered” and it is something we haven’t particularly seen deployed for anything other than core real estate since the Great Financial Crisis (“GFC”). 

The resulting market behavior is significant because when buyers who would normally utilize debt begin to transact without it, it can often signal the bottom of a real estate cycle. To the extent  I see more unlevered transactions occur in 2023 the more conviction I will have that true market clearing price discovery is occurring and that a floor is forming under asset prices. 

Saturday, January 7, 2023

Victory Over Russia in Ukraine May Bring World War 3: Niall Ferguson - Bloomberg

Victory Over Russia in Ukraine May Bring World War 3: Niall Ferguson - Bloomberg

All Is Not Quiet on the Eastern Front

2022 was the year in which war made a comeback. But Cold War II could become World War III in 2023 — with China as the arsenal of autocracy.

World warriors?

World warriors?

Photographer: Greg Baker/AFP/Getty Images

By

Niall Ferguson

January 1, 2023 at 5:00 AM GMT

headshot of Niall Ferguson

Niall Ferguson is a Bloomberg Opinion columnist. The Milbank Family Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University and the founder of Greenmantle, an advisory firm, he is author, most recently, of “Doom: The Politics of Catastrophe.” @nfergus

+ Get alerts forNiall Ferguson

War is hell on earth — and if you doubt it, visit Ukraine or watch Edward Berger’s All Quiet on the Western Front, Netflix’s gut-wrenching new adaptation of Erich Maria Remarque’s classic antiwar novel of 1929.

Even a small war is hellish for those caught up in it, of course. But a world war is the worst thing we humans have ever done to one another. In a memorable essay published last month, Henry Kissinger reflected on “How to Avoid Another World War.” In 1914, “The nations of Europe, insufficiently familiar with how technology had enhanced their respective military forces, proceeded to inflict unprecedented devastation on one another.” Then, after two years of industrialized slaughter, “the principal combatants in the West (Britain, France and Germany) began to explore prospects for ending the carnage.” Even with US intermediation, the effort failed.

More from

BloombergOpinion

 

Another World War Is No Longer Unthinkable

One Way the Speaker Fiasco Was Good for Republicans

Thanks for the Tanks, But Send the Abrams and Leopard Too

Pope Benedict and the Art of Strategic Retirement

Kissinger posed an important question: “Does the world today find itself at a comparable turning point [like the opportunity for peace in 1916] in Ukraine as winter imposes a pause on large-scale military operations there?” This time last year, I predicted that Russia would invade Ukraine. The question one year later is whether there is a way to end this war, or whether it is destined to grow into something much larger.

As Kissinger rightly points out, two nuclear-armed powers are currently contesting the fate of Ukraine. One side, Russia, is directly engaged in conventional warfare. However, the US and its allies are fighting indirectly by providing Ukraine with what Alex Karp, chief executive of Palantir Technologies Inc., calls “the power of advanced algorithmic warfare systems.” These are now so potent, he recently told the Washington Post’s David Ignatius, that they “equate to having tactical nuclear weapons against an adversary with only conventional ones.” Take a moment to ponder the implications of that.

War is back. Could world war also make a comeback? If so, it will affect all of our lives. In the second interwar era (1991-2019), we lost sight of the role of war in the global economy. Because the wars of that time were small (Bosnia, Afghanistan, Iraq), we forgot that war is history’s favorite driver of inflation, debt defaults — even famines. That is because large-scale war is simultaneously destructive of productive capacity, disruptive of trade, and destabilizing of fiscal and monetary policies.

But war is as much about the mobilization of real resources as it is about finance and money: Every great power needs to be able to feed its population and power its industry. In times of high interdependence (globalization), a great power needs to retain the option to revert to self-sufficiency in time of war. And self-sufficiency makes things more expensive than relying on free trade and comparative advantage.

Throughout history, the principal source of power is technological superiority in armaments, including intelligence and communications. A critical question is therefore: What are the key inputs without which a state-of-the-art military is unattainable?

In 1914, they were coal, iron and the manufacturing capacity to mass-produce artillery and shells, as well as steamships. In 1939, they were oil, steel, aluminum and the manufacturing capacity to mass-produce artillery, ships, submarines, planes and tanks. After 1945 it was all of the above, plus the scientific and technical capacity to produce nuclear weapons.

Today, the vital inputs are the capacity to mass-produce high-performance semiconductors, satellites, and the algorithmic warfare systems that depend on them.

What were the principal lessons of the 20th-century world wars? First, the American combination of technological and financial leadership, plus abundant natural resources, was impossible to beat. Secondly, however, the dominant Anglophone empires were poor at deterrence. The UK failed twice to dissuade Germany and its allies from gambling on world war. This was mainly because Liberal and Conservative governments alike were unwilling to ask voters for peacetime sacrifices, and they failed at statecraft. The result was two very expensive conflicts that cost much more in life and treasure than effective deterrence would have — and left the UK exhausted and unable to sustain its empire.

The US has been the dominant Anglophone empire since the Suez Crisis of 1956. With the threat of nuclear Armageddon, the US successfully deterred the Soviet Union from advancing its Marxist-Leninist empire in Europe much beyond the rivers Elbe and Danube. But America was relatively unsuccessful at preventing the spread of communism by Soviet-backed organizations and regimes in what was then known as the Third World.

The US is still bad at deterrence. Last year, it failed to deter President Vladimir Putin from invading Ukraine, mainly because it had low confidence in the Ukrainian defense forces it had trained and the Kyiv government that controlled them. The latest objective of American deterrence is Taiwan, a functionally autonomous democracy that China claims as its own. 

In October, President Joe Biden’s administration belatedly published its National Security Strategy. Such documents are always the work of a committee, but internal dissonance shouldn’t be this obvious. “The post-Cold War era is definitively over,” the authors declare, “and a competition is underway between the major powers to shape what comes next.” However, “we do not seek conflict or a new Cold War.” For the major powers have “shared challenges” such as climate change and Covid and other pandemic diseases.

On the other hand, “Russia poses an immediate threat to the free and open international system, recklessly flouting the basic laws of the international order today, as its brutal war of aggression against Ukraine has shown.” China, meanwhile, is “the only competitor with both the intent to reshape the international order and, increasingly, the economic, diplomatic, military and technological power to advance that objective.”

So what will the US do to check these rivals? The answer sounds remarkably similar to what it did in Cold War I:

·        “We will assemble the strongest possible coalitions to advance and defend a world that is free, open, prosperous and secure.”

·        “We will prioritize maintaining an enduring competitive edge over the PRC while constraining a still profoundly dangerous Russia.”

·        “We must ensure strategic competitors cannot exploit foundational American and allied technologies, know-how, or data to undermine American and allied security.”

In other words: form and maintain alliances and try to prevent the other side from catching up technologically. This is a cold war strategy in all but name.

US support for Ukraine since the Feb. 24 invasion has undoubtedly succeeded in weakening Putin’s regime. The Russian military has suffered disastrous losses of trained manpower and equipment. The Russian economy may not have contracted by as much as Washington hoped (a mere 3.4% last year, according to the International Monetary Fund), but Russian imports have crashed due to Western export controls. As Russia’s stock of imported component parts and machinery runs down, Russian industry will face deep disruptions, including in the defense and energy sectors.

Last year, Russia cut off gas exports to Europe that it cannot reroute, as there are no alternative pipelines. Putin thought the gas weapon would allow him to divide the West. So far, it has not worked. Russia also tried choking Black Sea grain exports. But that lever had little strategic value as the biggest losers of the blockade were poor African and Middle Eastern countries.

The net result of Putin’s war thus far has been to reduce Russia to something like an economic appendage of China, its biggest trading partner. And Western sanctions mean that what Russia exports to China is sold at a discount.

There are two obvious problems with US strategy, however. The first is that if algorithmic weapons systems are the equivalent of tactical nuclear weapons, Putin may eventually be driven to using the latter, as he clearly lacks the former. The second is that the Biden administration appears to have delegated to Kyiv the timing of any peace negotiations — and the preconditions the Ukrainians demand are manifestly unacceptable in Moscow.

The war therefore seems destined, like the Korean War in Cold War I, to drag on until a stalemate is reached, Putin dies and an armistice is agreed that draws a new border between Ukraine and Russia. The problem with protracted wars is that the US and European publics tend to get sick of them well before the enemy does.

China is a much tougher nut to crack than Russia. Whereas a proxy war is driving Russia’s economy and military back into the 1990s, the preferred approach to China is to stunt its technological growth, particularly with respect to — in the words of National Security Adviser Jake Sullivan — “computing-related technologies, including microelectronics, quantum information systems and artificial intelligence” and “biotechnologies and biomanufacturing.”

“On export controls,” Sullivan went on, “we have to revisit the longstanding premise of maintaining ‘relative’ advantages over competitors in certain key technologies.  We previously maintained a ‘sliding scale’ approach that said we need to stay only a couple of generations ahead. That is not the strategic environment we are in today.  Given the foundational nature of certain technologies, such as advanced logic and memory chips, we must maintain as large of a lead as possible.”

Sanctions on Russia, argued Sullivan, had “demonstrated that technology export controls can be more than just a preventative tool.” They can be “a new strategic asset in the US and allied toolkit.” Meanwhile, the US is going to ramp up its investment in home-produced semiconductors and related hardware.

The experience of Cold War I confirms that such methods can work. Export controls were part of the reason the Soviet economy could not keep pace with the US in information technology. The question is whether this approach can work against China, which is as much the workshop of the world today as America was in the 20th century, with a far broader and deeper industrial economy than the Soviet Union ever achieved.

Readers of the science-fiction novel The Three-Body Problem by Liu Cixin will recall that the aliens from the planet Trisolaris use intergalactic surveillance to halt technological advance on Earth while their invasion force makes its way through deep space. Can arresting China’s development really be how the US prevails in Cold War II?

True, recent Commerce Department restrictions — on the transfer of advanced graphics processing units to China, the use of American chips and expertise in Chinese supercomputers, and the export to China of chipmaking technology — pose major problems for Beijing. They essentially cut the People’s Republic off from all high-end semiconductor chips, including those made in Taiwan and Korea, as well as all chip experts who are “US persons,” which includes green-card holders as well as citizens.

It’s also true that there are no quick fixes for Chinese President Xi Jinping. Most of China’s fabrication capacity is at low-tech nodes (larger in size than 16 nanometers). He cannot conjure up overnight a mainland clone of Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Co.,  which leads the world in the sophistication of its chips. Nor can Xi expect that TSMC would conduct business as usual if China launched a successful invasion of Taiwan. The company’s chip fabs would almost certainly be destroyed in a war. Even if they survived, they could not function without TSMC personnel, who might flee, and equipment from the US, Japan and Europe, which would cease to be available.

Yet China has other cards it can play. It is dominant in the processing of minerals that are vital to the modern economy, including copper, nickel, cobalt and lithium. In particular, China controls over 70% of rare earth production both in terms of extraction and processing. These are 17 minerals used to make components in devices such as smartphones, electric vehicles, solar panels and semiconductors. An embargo on their export to the US might not be a lethal blow, but it would force the US and its allies to develop other sources in a hurry.

America’s Achilles heel is often seen as its unsustainable fiscal path. At some point in the coming decade, according to the Congressional Budget Office, interest payments on the federal debt are likely to exceed defense spending. Meanwhile, it is not immediately obvious who buys all the additional Treasuries issued each year if the Federal Reserve is engaged in quantitative tightening.

Might this give China an opportunity to exert financial pressure on the US? In July, it held $970 billion worth of Treasuries, making it the second-largest foreign holder of US debt. As has often been pointed out, if China chose to dump its Treasuries, it would drive up US bond yields and bring down the dollar, though not without causing considerable pain to itself.

Yet the bigger American vulnerability may be in the realm of resources rather than finance. The US long ago ceased to be a manufacturing economy. It has become a great importer from the rest of the world. As Matthew Suarez, a lieutenant in the US Marine Corps, points out in an insightful essay at American Purpose, that makes the nation heavily reliant on the world’s merchant marine. “Setting aside the movement of oil and bulk commodities,” Suarez writes, “most internationally traded goods travel in one of six million containers transported in approximately 61,000 ships. This flow of goods depends on an equally robust parallel flow of digital information.”

The growing dominance of China in both these areas should not be underestimated. Beijing’s Belt and Road Initiative has created infrastructure that reduces Chinese reliance on seaborne trade. Meanwhile, Shanghai Westwell Lab Information Technology Co. is rapidly becoming the leading vendor of the most advanced port-operating systems.

The war in Ukraine has provided a reminder that the disruption of trade is a vital weapon of war. It has also reminded us that a great power must be in a position to mass-produce modern weaponry, with or without access to imports. Both sides in the war have consumed staggering quantities of shells and missiles as well as armored vehicles and drones. The big question raised by any Chinese-American conflict is how long the US could sustain it.

As my Hoover Institution colleague Jackie Schneider has pointed out, just “four months of support to Ukraine … depleted much of the stockpile of such weapons, including a third of the US Javelin arsenal and a quarter of US Stingers.” According to the Royal United Services Institute, the artillery ammunition that the US currently produces in a year would have sufficed for only 10 days to two weeks of combat in Ukraine in the early phase of the war.

A February 2022 Department of Defense report on industrial capacity warned that the US companies producing tactical missiles, fixed-wing aircraft and satellites had reduced their output by more than half.

As I have pointed out elsewhere, the US today is in some ways in the situation of the British Empire in the 1930s. If it repeats the mistakes successive UK governments made in that decade, a fiscally overstretched America will fail to deter a nascent Axis-like combination of Russia, Iran and China from risking simultaneous conflict in three theaters: Eastern Europe, the Middle East and the Far East. The difference is that there will be no sympathetic industrial power to serve as the “arsenal of democracy” — a phrase used by President Franklin D. Roosevelt in a radio broadcast on Dec. 29, 1940. This time it is the autocracies that have the arsenal.

The Biden administration must be exceedingly careful not to pursue economic warfare against China so aggressively that Beijing finds itself in the position of Japan in 1941, with no better option than to strike early and hope for military success. This would be very dangerous indeed, as China’s position today is much stronger than Japan’s was then.

Kissinger is right to worry about the perils of a world war. The first and second world wars were each preceded by smaller conflicts: the Balkan Wars of 1912 and 1913, the Italian invasion of Abyssinia (1936), the Spanish Civil War (1936-39), the Sino-Japanese War (1937). The Russian invasion of Ukraine may seem to be going well for the West right now. But in a worst-case scenario, it could be a similar harbinger of a much wider war.

More From This Writer at Bloomberg Opinion:

·        The Four Mysteries of Pelosi’s Troublesome Taiwan Trip: Niall Ferguson

·        The World’s Cascade of Disasters Is Not a Coincidence: Niall Ferguson

·        The Fed Hasn’t Fixed Its Worst Blunder Since the 1970s: Niall Ferguson

 


Friday, January 6, 2023

The Nokia Risk | Phenomenal World

The Nokia Risk | Phenomenal World

The Nokia Risk

Small countries, big firms, and the end of the fifth Schumpetarian wave

In the early 2000s, Finland was the darling of industrial and employment policy analysts everywhere. This small country with a population of 5.5 million and a GDP roughly equal to the state of Oregon experienced what looked like a high tech-led productivity revolution. Real GDP per capita in local currency terms rose 55 percent from 1995 to 2007—nearly double the US increase and close to the pinnacle of the twenty-one richest OECD industrialized economies. 

Yet spectacular growth abruptly halted after 2008. GDP continued to rise with population growth, but from 2008 to 2019 real Finnish per capita income declined. The European Central Bank’s dilatory response to the eurozone crisis, and the austerity policies that followed, undoubtedly explain part of this abysmal performance. But an equally large part is due to Finland having many of its growth eggs in a single basket: Nokia. Nokia’s handsets and related telephony equipment accounted for 20 percent of Finnish exports at peak, driving Finland’s current account surplus to nearly 7 percent of GDP.1 When the Apple iPhone launched in 2007, Nokia’s handset market collapsed, exports fell by half, Finland’s current account swung into deficit, and a decade plus of economic stagnation began.

Finland is not the only economy facing “Nokia risk.” A larger group of seven countries—all of them relatively small, rich, and with stable governments—are similarly exposed. In Denmark, Israel, South Korea, Sweden, Switzerland, and Taiwan a handful of firms account for a hugely disproportionate share of both profits and R&D spending. The firms which dominate these seven economies have all been extraordinarily successful in the knowledge economy of the past three decades: Samsung Electronics in Korea, Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Co. in Taiwan, Novo Nordisk (pharmaceuticals) in Denmark, and Roche and Novartis (pharmaceuticals) in Switzerland. For the decade of 2011–2020, these firms have had large shares of cumulative profits both domestically and abroad. It is largely thanks to these profits that these small countries have such a significant share of global profit (larger than their share of global GDP) and, in turn, a relatively high per capita income. 

Table 1 shows the ratio of the share of cumulative global profit and of R&D expenditures to country share of global GDP, with some comparisons to the larger rich OECD countries. The figures are based on 21,580 global ultimate owners (headquarters firms) with annual sales averaging at least $10 million between 2011 and 2020, and which have enough comprehensive financial data to make comparison possible. While this calculation excludes a big chunk of small and medium sized industries (or SMEs, firms with fewer than 250 employees), these 21,580 are the biggest among the 41 million in the Bureau van Dijk Orbis database. The handful of firms discussed here is thus both mathematically and macroeconomically significant, as the very long tail of SMEs typically depends on those larger firms for their revenue. For example, Danish pharmaceutical giant Novo Nordisk alone accounts for a quarter of cumulative profits for the 200 plus Danish firms in Table 1; its 0.2 percent share of cumulative profits for all 21,580 firms is almost 50 times the average for that group.

Table 1: Ratio of share of cumulative Profit and R&D spending to share of Global GDP, by country, 2011–2020

 ProfitR&D# of firms
Taiwan2.834.07591
Sweden2.182.24360
Switzerland2.004.89131
Denmark1.941.05222
Korea1.632.10706
Finland1.153.05185
Israel0.531.07101
For comparison:
Norway1.800.24253
Japan1.583.072694
USA1.451.752524
Germany0.971.701274
Source: Author calculation from Bureau van Dijk Orbis database and IMF World Economic Outlook database

In the coming years, these firms and the national economies that house them will confront two big challenges. On the economic front, the fifth Schumpeterian growth wave, which was built on information and communication technologies (ICT) as well as traditional and first-generation bio-engineered pharmaceuticals, has exhausted much of its growth impulse. A potential sixth wave built on artificial intelligence (AI), machine learning (ML), and second-generation biotech (CRISPR) as general-purpose technologies threatens these firms’ existing production systems and markets. At the same time, governments everywhere are ramping up antitrust and other attacks on visible monopolies, and edging towards more nationalistic industrial and trade policy. In light of the central role of these firms that account for disproportionate shares of their home economy exports, failure to navigate these challenges will result in a major economic shock for their small, rich countries. 

Schumpetarian waves and industrial transitions

Joseph Schumpeter’s analysis of dynamic change in capitalist economies—what he termed “creative destruction”— sheds light on the economic risks facing the core firms in these seven economies. Schumpeter argued that the central puzzle in economics was explaining the sources of dynamic growth. In an economy that actually embodied the starting assumptions of mainstream economics—small, competitive firms with no barriers to entry and no pricing power—profits would fall to the cost of capital plus some managerial wage for owner-operators. In essence, profits would only cover depreciation. Consequently, extensive and intensive growth would slow to the rate of population growth plus some gains from the normal productivity creep that incremental innovation produced for firms—in short, the kind of economic slump that prompted the secular stagnation debate of the 2010s. This circular economy, as Schumpeter called it, would never produce the periodic eruptions of rapid technological change and growth that he observed in the two centuries after the industrial revolution. As he put it, in these circumstances, you could add as many stagecoaches as you wanted to the economy but never get to a railroad.

Dynamic growth required radical innovation in five key, interconnected areas: new modes of transportation, new energy sources, new consumer goods, new general purpose production technologies, and, though he underemphasized this, new legal organization or governance structures for firms. Writing on the eve of the Second World War, Schumpeter identified four such revolutions that had so far taken place. The first initiated the industrial revolution, centering on canals, water mills, textiles, and other household nondurables, with small owner-operated factories collecting handicraft producers under one roof. The second, in the mid-1800s, focused on steam power, railroads, and iron goods, as well as larger but still owner-operated factories using custom made machinery. The third, towards the end of the 1800s, emerged from electricity, steel steamships, urban trams, bicycles and chemicals, and saw the rise of large corporations which began to separate ownership and management. The fourth wave centered on internal combustion engines for land and air transport, petroleum, mass consumption of consumer durables like vehicles, continuous flow-assembly line production, and vertically integrated and often multidivisional firms with full separation of ownership and management. This wave began in the United States, most famously with Ford’s Model T, and spread to Europe and Japan. The transition periods between each of these growth spurts all saw increased domestic or international conflict and decreased investment in ageing growth sectors. Thus the transition from wave three to wave four saw the beginning of industrial unions and coincided with rising interimperial conflict that eventually produced World War I.

The fifth wave began in the US in the 1960s with the development of the semiconductor chip, and soon spread globally. It is based on connectivity via electronics (ICT), negative energy consumption via digitalization, pharmaceuticals and first-generation biotechnologies, software and semiconductors, global supply chains, and de jure vertically disintegrated firms with de facto control by lead firms. This era’s iconic product, the smartphone, embodies the whole range of electronics products developed from the 1940s onward in a compact and relatively cheap form. 

There are many reasons to think this fifth wave is nearing exhaustion. Smartphone sales levelled off in 2018 and then declined somewhat, signalling replacement sales rather than growth. Despite the annual iPhone launch hype, most of the improvements to smartphones in recent years are largely marginal. Roughly 80 percent of the world’s population has 4G access—if they can pay for it. The entire global electronics industry is linked to personal computers and smartphones, which account for roughly half of global chip sales. Similarly, new pharmaceutical discovery levelled off in the 2000s, with most new drugs being copies or modifications of older drugs.2 

But sales volumes simply reflect more important trends. Several key technologies and industries have already emerged in the energy and transportation space as well as, albeit with less clarity, in production software and pharmaceuticals.3 Alternative and renewable energy sources are clearly replacing fossil fuels as the basis for electricity generation and equipment power, including the critical transportation sector. And AI and ML appear to be general purpose production technologies reshaping both biotechnology (along with the new CRISPR-Cas gene editing technology) and the organization of machinery production. Table 2 summarizes the economic and political risks this sixth wave poses for core firms in these seven economies.

Table 2: Economic and political risks facing core Seven Samurai firms

CountryFirmSectorPolitical RiskEconomic Risk
DenmarkNovo NordiskPharmaceuticalsRegulation of Insulin pricesAI based genomics shifts value to personalized drugs
H. LundbeckPharmaceuticalsRegulation of Insulin pricesAI based genomics
VestasEnergy – windmillsNational champions in other countriesGrowth potential is high
FinlandNokiaTelecom equipment5G becomes a national security issueAI & ML shift value to software
IsraelTevaPharmaceuticalsPrice regulation in generalAI based genomics
KoreaSamsungMemory chips; phonesPolicy driven on-shoring by US and EUAI design shifts more value to systems on a chip
HyundaiVehiclesElectrificationAI shifts value to battery management software & driver aids
SwedenEricssonTelecom equipment5G becomes a national security issueSoftware-based switching systems replace hardware-based systems
Volvo (Trucks)VehiclesElectrificationAI shifts value to battery management software & driver aids
ABB, Assa Abloy, SandvikMachinery FirmsDeglobalization, EV effects on German car industryAI & ML shift value to software; EV requires fewer parts
SwitzerlandNovartisPharmaceuticalsPrice regulation in generalAI based genomics
RochePharmaceuticalsPrice regulation in generalAI based genomics
TaiwanTSMCSemiconductor fabricationPolicy driven on-shoring by US and EU; warSubsidized national champions
Hon Hai PrecisionElectronics assemblyUS-China tensionsAI design shifts more value to systems on a chip, simplifying assembly
Source: Author assessment

Calculating risk

Creating the huge reticulation networks that made new energy and transport sources useful required equally huge investments. One mile of railroad was pointless, 100 miles was revolutionary. Schumpeter, in his earlier works, argued that only entrepreneurs hyping potential monopoly profits could induce bankers to finance these huge investments. He called this the Mark I model, in which small start-up firms run by visionaries upend existing incumbents. Many of the current software giants fit this pattern, but it also characterized the earliest days of Ford. Later, Schumpeter noted that high-profit corporations could channel their monopoly profits to dedicated internal research labs and generate the same kind of revolutionary innovation—his Mark II innovation model. Here, think of ATT’s Bell Labs, which invented the transistor. 

Software aside, we largely live in a world that combines both Mark I and Mark II innovation in a complex web that mostly favors larger firms. Typically, states promote radical innovation, often by funding basic research in university labs and their small firms spin-offs—classic Mark I innovation. But larger firms then typically provide those small firms with more funding to develop a commercializable product that their own Mark II R&D teams will perfect. While these smaller firms often get the publication glory, the larger firms usually get the bulk of patents and thus profits. Apple’s SIRI assistant, initially developed by a US-wide research team organized through the Stanford University’s Research Institute on behalf of the Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency (DARPA), was absorbed by Apple into its own software ecosystem. 

If profits and R&D were evenly distributed across firms in each of our seven economies, these new technologies might not pose so big threat. But under the present combination of Mark I and Mark II innovation, a handful of firms account for the bulk of profits and R&D. For example, insulin accounts for roughly 7 percent of cumulative Danish goods exports for the period 2002–2021, with most of this coming from the pharmaceutical giant Novo Nordisk. 80 percent of Novo Nordisk’s revenue comes from sales of insulin and diabetes-related products, but 80 percent of Denmark’s workforce is in the service sector, which apart from Maersk-Møller and Legoland largely does not generate exports. Thus, the fate of Novo Nordisk has the potential to impact one of the country’s only significant export sectors. 

Table 3 shows the degree to which this very narrow slice of firms dominates both profitability and R&D in our group of seven economies. The table thus captures the degree of vulnerability around Mark II innovation. Comprehensive data on Mark I innovation—which ranges from a handful of people tinkering in their parents’ garage to modestly sized start-ups with no revenue—is not available. As noted above, Schumpeter’s two pathways to radical innovation are more intermingled today than in the past, when vertically integrated firms were rather sealed off from both universities and small firms. These days, much Mark I innovation is often captured by the larger firms through acqui-hires, acquisition, or copycat innovation and litigation. Equally so, accurate, comparable data on the relative share of national profits by firm size is not available. While the $10 million annual operating revenue metric is biased towards fairly large firms, it does reach into the upper end of the long tail of SMEs that constitute the majority of firms in most countries. Moreover, SMEs typically have labor productivity levels one-third below larger firms. 

Table 3: Firm share of cumulative national R&D and profits for high R&D firms, 2004–2020

CompanyR&D shareProfit share
DenmarkNovo Nordisk34.6%35%
FinlandNokia77.6%19%
IsraelTeva Pharmaceutical 43.9%7.6%
Elbit Systems9.1%8.3%
KoreaSamsung Electronics47.1%36.6%
Hyundai Motor8.3%7.4%
SwedenEricsson38.7%7.9%
Volvo (trucks)19.8%10%
SwitzerlandRoche33.4%23.7%
Novartis29.7%16%
TaiwanTaiwan Semiconductor12.6%29.1%
Hon Hai Precision Industry12%14.2%
Source: Author calculation from European Commission data at https://iri.jrc.ec.europa.eu/data

These large firms dominate exports, and thus generate the foreign exchange needed to buy the considerable volume of goods and services that the seven economies do not produce locally. Given their small size, these economies cannot attain a domestic division of labor that generates the bulk of their consumption—hence their need for export. In all but one of the countries, firms with more than 250 employees account for more than half of exports. Denmark is the exception; there the share is so close to half that it makes no difference (data for Taiwan are not available, but as noted above TSMC’s large share suggests the pattern of large firm dominance is not much different). Table 3 understates the importance of the larger firms, as these typically account for fewer than 1 percent of the total count of firms, while firms with fewer than 10 employees account for over 90 percent. 

As noted above, these few dominant firms largely explain why these societies capture a larger share of global profit than their share of global GDP (Table 1), which in turn explains why they are relatively rich societies. Success in generating high-value exports and their associated profits permits these societies to exchange a small volume of high-value exports for a much larger volume of lower-value imports. This disproportionate profit share reflects both pluck—local ability in the form of prior investments in R&D and human capital—as well as the broader dynamics of the modern economy.

These firms rely on their investments in R&D to maintain their competitiveness. Their investments in turn explain the above average share of R&D in their economies as compared with the larger economies of the G7. Table 4 provides four relevant pieces of information. It contrasts R&D spending and the number of full-time researchers in the population relative to the G7 countries. It also shows the high share of total R&D by business, as well as the disproportionate share of total R&D spending accounted for by both the largest and the fifth largest firms and thus their even greater share of business R&D (the picture is somewhat different in the case of Taiwan). Table 4 thus shows the degree to which future innovation—at least in terms of the Mark II innovation that turns Mark I innovation into a global product—rests on a very narrow foundation. We could construct an index of risk by multiplying the share of business R&D by the share of the top one or five firms, but this would give a false sense of precision. The central point here—looking at the last two columns—is one of amazing concentration of research spending.

The overlap of high profitability and profit share, export share and R&D share, is not accidental. It indicates past competitiveness and near monopoly or dominant positions in world markets. Profits fund the R&D that enables dominance and thus continued above average shares of global profits; those profits fund high levels of per capita income—among others, all those researcher jobs. And they fund, in some cases, extensive welfare states or at least state-education funding that generates the human capital those researchers possess, and which is the basis for past and potentially future dominance in high-tech sectors. Thus, for example, between 1991 and 2000, Swedish education spending increased by 2.1 percentage points of GDP to 7.4 percent, with half of that going to tertiary education. The Nordics have significantly higher literacy scores in standardized international tests than the rest of the rich countries, though Sweden has recently slipped back.4

Table 4: R&D intensity of economy, various measures, percent, average as indicated, ranked by column 1

R&D percent of GDPFTE researchers per 1000 workersBusiness percent of R&DTop 1 share of Business R&DTop 5 share of Business R&D
2010-20192010-20192010-20192005-20202005-2020
Israel4.3685.743.969.5
Korea4.0215.978.147.172.2
Sweden3.2515.269.538.768.8
Switzerland3.178.6 71.233.478.3*
Finland3.11567.477.685.8
Taiwan3.0813.876.612.639.3
Denmark2.9914.164.734.659.2
Unweighted G7 Average2.278.7165.4
FTE = full time equivalent; * top 2 = 63.1 percent.
Source: Columns 1–3 OECD Main Science and Technology Indicators https://www.oecd.org/sti/msti.htm; 4–5 EU data https://iri.jrc.ec.europa.eu/data

The franchise economy

The shift from the fourth (mass production) to the fifth (ICT) Schumpeterian wave involved changes in corporate strategy and structure that had significant knock-on effects. Chief among them, it boosted income inequality and increased the degree to which firms’ profitability depended on the legal regime around intellectual property (IPRs—patent, copyright, brand, and trademark). In the Fordist era, corporate strategy aimed at monopoly or oligopoly profits through control over large masses of physical capital arranged into continuous flow, assembly line systems. Profitability rested on running those systems at something close to their full capacity. This pushed firms to vertically integrate and negotiate peace with their typically unionized labor forces, which in turn reduced income inequality and funded internal research labs.

But as more and more firms adopted this vertically integrated, unionized structure, profits began to decline. Workers revolted against the monotony and pace of assembly line production, and decolonization enabled raw-materials producers to push up prices, disrupting energy and metals markets. Put simply, once everyone adopted a Fordist product and production structure, the world ran out of cheap oil and docile semi-skilled assembly-line workers. 

Firms reacted to this militance by changing their corporate structure. They shrank their labor forces and opted to subcontract or offshore their low-wage, low-skill workforce. Similarly, they expelled physical assets—machines—used for producing undifferentiated goods into spin-off firms, as when GM and Ford created Delphi (now Aptiv) and Visteon as parts producers. At the same time, they began seeking more durable monopolies based on IPRs produced by a labor force high in human capital and supported by an army of subcontractors. This shift, which both coincided with and enabled the emergence of the fifth Schumpeterian wave, produced what I call a franchise structure.

In the franchise economy, lead firms with lots of human capital, few actual employees, and substantial intellectual property portfolios outsource much of production to two other generic types of subordinated firms. Second layer firms are typically more capital-intensive firms with some barrier to entry for their production processes. Third layer firms are labor intensive firms producing undifferentiated goods and services. The lead firm orchestrates almost everything in its value chain without bearing any of the risk of holding that physical capital or dealing with masses of workers. In our seven economies, the lead firms are all among the country’s largest, albeit sometimes hybrids of the top two layers. Profitability for those firms derives from their control of intellectual property rights. Nokia, for example, lives on as a producer of network hardware and software based on earlier and ongoing R&D that generated more than 10,000 US patents from 2000 to 2019. Unlike the barrier to entry posed by capital intensive production, patents are vulnerable to radical technological change and also radical change in the legal regime surrounding the patent

While the shift to a franchise structure was good for firms with robust IPR portfolios and, by extension, for the high human-capital intensity of the workforce of our seven economies, it was less good for workers and firms producing undifferentiated goods and services. Downsizing meant shifting relatively well-paying jobs to low-wage countries, hollowing out the middle of the income distribution. Between 1998 and 2016, for example, Sweden’s industrial giants cut their workforce from 80,000 to 49,000 people. While younger labor market entrants into more IPR-based firms partly compensated for this, the loss of so many mid-level jobs has had broad socioeconomic effects, arguably contributing to the rise of anti-immigrant parties in the country. Nativist policies, in turn, threaten the ability of firms to attract the global talent they need to sustain R&D.

Coping with risk

Danish industrial policy with regard to pharmaceuticals illustrates the tensions around both Mark I and Mark II types of innovation strategy. Recent Danish governments have promoted Denmark as an “innovation country” and formed a “Disruption Council” intended to preserve the country’s economic position. Danish R&D is highly concentrated in the pharmaceutical and biomedical sector (Vestas’ windmill production and servicing provides a side bet on alternative energy, but Chinese competition squeezes profitability). A government-run public goods strategy supports the emergence of Mark I type firms in biotechnology, thus providing a “feedstock” for Mark II oriented Novo Nordisk. This strategy continues a long tradition of “extension” type services designed to bring new technology and best practices from universities and high performing firms to more traditional firms including manufacturing SMEs. It is supplemented with venture capital from the Danish Growth Fund (Vækstfonden). The policy has helped keep Danish firms largely at the technology frontier, producing a narrower gap between leading and lagging firms than in the rest of the OECD. But the challenge in pharmaceuticals is anticipating the bio-genomics revolution rather than adapting to it.

In cooperation with Novo Nordisk, the Danish government runs a cluster of data collection and dissemination organizations: the Danish National Genome Center (Nationalt Genom Center), the National Biobank (Danmarks Nationale Biobank under the State Serum Institute), and the overarching Royal Bio and Genome Bank. These centers leverage the comprehensive and diachronic data the state collects from all hospitals and practitioners on a large range of conditions and patient variables. For example, the Biobank currently has serum samples from nearly 1 million people and 25 million samples in toto. The Genome Center was able to establish a genomic sequence database for distinguishing Covid-19 variants within five days in March 2020. Quite apart from the value to Novo Nordisk (which accounts for 90 percent of Danish pharmaceutical employment and profits), the databanks also enable smaller biotech firms to access large volumes of data on relatively smaller (in terms of incidence) diseases and thus help them overcome one major research hurdle. Put simply, they generate and hold the data that machine-learning and AI driven R&D projects need to function. Novo Nordisk meanwhile acts as a central contractor with many smaller research-oriented firms—though these contracts generally choke off growth from Mark I innovation in favor of pre-emption by the lead firm. Overall, however, Denmark lacks indigenous AI and ML firms that might supply expertise to the entire sector, as compared with either Israel or Sweden.

Those countries display different strategies with different weaknesses. Israel’s huge defense related investment in software and sensor capacity created a vibrant Mark I-type tech sector. But Israelis doing that Mark I innovation typically sell their firms or technology to US Mark II type firms, as when Google bought the navigation firm Waze or when Intel acquired Mobileye, which develops autonomous driving technologies. The relative absence of big domestic tech firms explains Israel’s deviation from the broader pattern of profit share being above GDP share (Table 1). It also explains why so many Israelis—an estimated 100,000simply migrate to Silicon Valley even though Israel’s so-called Silicon Wadi usually houses more start-up firms per capita than any other country. Both trends potentially inhibit a response to the AI and ML revolution in software. The Israeli state, meanwhile, has relaxed the stringent employment and production requirements it put in place to stimulate Silicon Wadi in the first place.

By contrast, Sweden has an abundance of large, mature Mark II type firms. Yet these have gradually hollowed out actual production in favor of simply generating intellectual property. The extreme case here is Volvo. Its old automobile capacity was sold first to Ford and then to the Chinese holding company Zhejiang Geely.5 Geely relies on Swedish engineering talent to design the new Volvo electric vehicle line (including Polestar), but production has largely shifted outside of Sweden. Similarly, Swedish pharmaceutical giants Pharmacia and Astra respectively ended up controlled by Pfizer (USA) and AstraZeneca (UK). As noted above, the big Swedish manufacturing firms have steadily reduced employment. Like Israel, Sweden is increasingly a hunting ground for foreign multinational firms looking for talented individuals. This sustains high-wage employment—at least for some. But it also means the profits end up somewhere else, and large Mark II firms that might anchor a research network are harder to form. 

High tides

The sixth Schumpeterian wave, should it indeed appear, poses serious risks for the largest, export-focused firms of our seven economies. Presently, a narrow set of IPR-based firms in the Mark II model does the forward-looking investment in R&D that enables the transformation and scaling up of Mark I innovation required to catch that wave. It also generates both the jobs and the revenues needed to sustain a politically acceptable level of imports, employment, and growth in general. The potential inability of the big, highly profitable firms that anchor local research ecosystems to transition from their current production model to the novel production models emerging will have serious consequences. 

This risk extends beyond the “innovator’s dilemma.” Domestically, the loss of core manufacturing jobs in the second layer of the franchise economy has provoked populist backlashes. In both Israel and Sweden, this has empowered parties hostile to state-led industrial policy favoring highly paid knowledge workers. Externally, growing geopolitical tension between the United States and China has prompted efforts to reshore or “near-shore” the ICT sector, particularly semiconductor production. All told, this probably tilts the global playing field towards firms from the larger and more geopolitically powerful countries. As noted above, those firms already fish in the human-capital pools of the seven economies of our study, potentially undermining the survival or emergence of Mark II firms that anchor local R&D and production ecosystems. If the winner-take-all nature of the franchise economy continues, these older firms must run fast simply to stay in place. 

For the pawns of the global economy—smaller economies without national champions like Nokia or Samsung, and without oil-fund assets as in Norway—these challenges are even more pronounced. They enter this race with greater headwinds, weighed down by external debt, relatively untrained workers, and, in the worst cases, an over-reliance on unprocessed raw materials exports.

  1. All data on exports are from the UN International Trade Center. Data on R&D are from the European Commission database on the 2500 largest R&D spenders in any given year from 2004 through 2019. This cumulates to 5303 firms over 56 countries and territorial units.

    ↩
  2. That said—as we will note below—a rising share of drug approvals concern bio-similars rather than the traditional small molecule pharmaceuticals.

    ↩
  3. The US state is already organizing policy around this. See remarks by National Security Advisor Jake Sullivan in September 2022.

    ↩
  4. Data supplied by John Stephens, University of North Carolina.

    ↩
  5. Not to be confused with AB Volvo, now largely a heavy truck manufacturer after spinning out Volvo Cars.

    ↩